What are the economic costs of ill-functioning Indian land markets? The news and public policy discussions on land often revolve around land acquisition by governments, like the Tata Nano Singur case or the Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation, and Resettlement Act of 2013. But the use of, or lack thereof, eminent domain stems from fundamental problems that make Indian land markets malfunction.

Sources of land frictions

The sources of malfunctioning or frictions with the land markets are many. Like many South and South-East Asian countries, India’s complicated inheritance system has resulted in small land parcels, with land fragmentation increasing over time. The average landholding size among land zoned for agricultural purposes was 1.1 hectares (2.7 acres) in 2015, down from 2.3 hectares (5.7 acres) in 1971.

In addition to small parcels, unclear land titles and slow-moving courts make buying land in India inherently risky. Furthermore, regulations around land rezoning, particularly buying land historically zoned for agricultural use, involve lengthy bureaucratic and legal hurdles.

Frictions in the land markets affect many aspects of the Indian economy. For example, the ill-functioning land markets affect the growth and shape of Indian cities, internal migration, infrastructure development, crop choice, farmer incomes, manufacturing productivity and growth, and the economy’s structural transformation.

Consequences in agriculture, manufacturing

Sixty-eight per cent of farm holdings in India are considered marginal farms — less than 1 hectare (or 2.5 acres in size). In contrast, Pakistan and the United States have 36% and 0% marginal farms, respectively. In conjunction with policies and regulations, small farm sizes make land consolidation difficult and have a detrimental effect on agricultural productivity.

For example, research has shown that strict land tenancy laws adopted post-Independence have resulted in lower rental market participation levels and, thus, reduced farm productivity by 38% on average. Another consequence is that these marginal farms cannot adequately mechanise, efficiently grow cash crops, and benefit from returns to scale.

Manufacturing firm growth in India is a central development challenge. Only 2% of Indian manufacturing firms have ten or more workers, compared with 8% and 40% of firms in Mexico and the US, respectively. This is problematic because larger firms generate more employment, especially for low-education workers. Larger firms (10 or more workers) employ 35% of Indian manufacturing workers, compared to 78% of Mexican manufacturing workers.

Among other aspects, a potential reason manufacturing firms cannot grow in India is land market frictions. A firm trying to expand or open a new factory unit has to negotiate over hundreds of landowners with unclear land titles to acquire adequate land for their factories. This is especially the case for firms in land-intensive industries like transportation equipment and chemicals manufacturing.

Consider an illustrative example of land aggregation for an automobile plant in the US and India. For its Fort Wayne auto plant in Indiana, General Motors acquired 379 hectares (936 acres) of land from 29 owners in two months. By contrast, consider the infamous case of the Tata Nano plant, where the government of West Bengal combined 404 hectares (997 acres) of land by aggregating over 13,970 land parcels owned by 12,000 landholders.

My research finds that in response to these land frictions, manufacturing firms aggregate land in what I call the small land bite strategy. They accumulate parcels slowly over time in small land bites, sometimes waiting for years before they have adequate land to build.

Private firms add land in smaller bites than government-affiliated firms. In addition, they must take more land bites over the years before building on it. Firms in states with smaller land parcels like Bihar and West Bengal also employ the small land bite strategy, unlike firms in states like Punjab and Gujarat, where land fragmentation is lower.

Moreover, firms have to bear substantial aggregation costs over and above land sale price. These costs result from search costs, negotiation efforts, and lawyer fees. Land aggregation costs come in two forms: fixed and variable costs. If the sheer endeavor to aggregate land is so costly that no matter how much land one gets, it is expensive to do so, then fixed costs are high. On the other hand, variable costs increase with the size of the land.

With data on land purchases by manufacturing firms for two decades, we can quantify the land aggregation costs for manufacturing firms. In the case of Indian land aggregation, the variable costs matter much more than fixed costs. The per-hectare variable land aggregation costs increase with the size of land needed. Hence, the costs are higher for larger firms. This is a consequence of both land fragmentation and unclear land titles.

Private firms pay up to three times higher costs than government-affiliated firms. On average, firms in states with smaller parcels and more land-related court cases pay higher land aggregation costs. In some states, firms pay almost twice for land aggregation costs, over and above the sale price for the land. My research only quantifies the land aggregation costs for industries, but farmers and city developers also pay similar land aggregation costs.

Policy efforts

What is the path forward? First, we must acknowledge that substantive farming on marginal farmlands provides economic security and is the only source of income for millions of households, even if that land is not used productively. However, even if we only cared about maximising the benefit of marginal farmers, there is no reason that policies that would aid in land consolidation within agriculture are illegal in India today.

However, suppose a hypothetical social planner were to maximise the gross return on land across different potential land uses. In that case, it is essential to recognise that several marginal farms are one of the most significant sources of friction.

This does not mean that we return to the days of land acquisition, which was both unfair and politically challenging, but was a shortcut to bypass the land aggregation costs. A market solution, where agents bargain and exchange land until there are no more gains from trade, is unlikely to work in India, given the scale of land aggregation frictions. This leaves us with two prospects.

The first prospect is land pooling policies that many state governments are currently attempting at different scales. Land pooling policies will certainly lower manufacturing firms’ overall costs and increase their growth rates.

However, under this policy, state governments will absorb the land aggregation costs previously paid by manufacturing firms. These costs are only worthwhile if there is adequate growth and employment generated by manufacturing firms to whom pooled land is leased. It is also important to note that land pooling procedures that allow discretion are ripe for crony procurement pitfalls.

The second prospect is to lower the land aggregation costs, reducing the overall costs for the government and private land aggregators alike. To so do, the government has already started the first step of digitising old paper records. Ninety-four per cent of 302 million records of registrations are already digitised.

In addition, 13.5% of the village land maps have been resurveyed, although whether these map records are linked with the records of registrations and court system varies across states. Once these fundamental hurdles of digitising and resurveying are cleared, land fragmentation will continue to pose significant challenges for land aggregation, albeit to a lower extent.

Aradhya Sood is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Management at the University of Toronto at Scarborough and the Rotman School of Management at the University of Toronto.

The article was first published on India in Transition, a publication of the Center for the Advanced Study of India, University of Pennsylvania.